Below the fold is a case study on the PBL setup I used for EC6012 last year. I wrote a paper about it, and presented it at a conference. Now it's a case study.
Some version of the stuff below the fold should be available on the economics network in a few days.
Update: The finished article is here. That was quick!
Teaching Structuralist Economics Using Problem
Based Learning and Weblogs
Department of Economics,
Kemmy Business School,
University of Limerick, Ireland
stephen.kinsella@ul.ie
www.stephenkinsella.net
1 Problem
Teaching post-Keynesian monetary economics is not easy. The lecturer has to
overcome the natural apprehension masters students must feel when faced with
completely new material, which purports to rewrite much of what they already think
they know about macroeconomics. Students will ask of their orthodox courses,
”Was all that hard work in vain? Surely not”. The lecturer must justify the
use of seemingly familiar concepts in different ways to the students. There
is less textbook-style material to draw from, and structuralist models are
generally more complex, inviting, as they do, more reality into the average
model than more orthodox models. Time considerations usually preclude a
parallel treatment of economic issues using orthodox models all the way
through the module. Also, because the focus of the course was primarily
technical rather than a survey or history of economic thought-based module, the
content was likely to be harder than most students had been exposed to
previously.
The lecturer must have an answer for each of these issues. A large amount of
effort must be expended in comparing and contrasting the orthodox macroeconomics
learnt from textbooks on macroeconomics like Barro00A0;(2007) and Barro and
Sala-i Martin00A0;(2003) to justify one’s approach and contextualise unfamiliar
course material for the students. One spends significant amounts of class
time simply setting the basics up before the real benefits of post-Keynesian
macroeconomic modeling—dealing with uncertainty, business cycles, and
behavioural actors through their generation of stocks and flows of funds—become
apparent. Unless great care is taken, all but the best students are left behind to
muddle through as best they can. The course creates confusion, annoyance and
frustration and exposes the lecturer to the dreaded ”so what?” from their
students.
Godley and Lavoie00A0;(2006) have written a masters-level textbook that
reduces many of these costs. As they progress through the book, Godley and
Lavoie build models of increasing complexity from a basic methodological
premise: the decisions and actions of economic actors (banks, households,
governments, etc) create financial stocks and flows which must be accounted for in
the aggregate. This aggregate is the macroeconomy. Macroeconomics is a
series of explanations of how these accounting entities influence one another
through time, in the presence of endogenous money, fundamental uncertainty,
and differing expectations. Each macroeconomic model, then, is the set of
behavioural equations imposed by the modeler on the national accounts which
hold the information created by the economic actors as they go about their
businesses.
Each model is developed from a simplified balance sheet and transactions matrix
which records the stocks accruing to each actor and the flows between them. A set of
dynamic behavioural equations is posited effectively determining the direction of the
financial flows between the actors. Steady state conditions are derived, and the
simulated equilibrium system is shocked under various scenarios to test differing
actor and national response to changing policies or economic conditions. Each of
these simulations is available online to allow students to verify the authors’ claims for
themselves.
2 Problem Based Learning
I set out to teach a masters-level course using Godley and Lavoie’s textbook as a
guide. The details of the course (lecture notes, podcasts, student blogs, etc) are here.
I decided to use Problem Based Learning as the key to these new techniques and this
new modeling methodology.
Problem-Based Learning (PBL) methods have been used in medical
education for some time (Barrows,00A0;1986;00A0;Delisle,00A0;1997) and in economics,
PBL techniques were recently applied to US high-school students in
macroeconomics (Maxwell et00A0;al.,00A0;2004,00A0;2005;00A0;Sharp,00A0;2003). Given the potential
benefits1
of this style of teaching, a module was designed to try out this method
on a postgraduate economics class, but with an added twist—the PBL
methods would be used to introduce students to the concepts of structuralist
macroeconomics, and most of the group work would be conducted via
weblogs2 .
The class had 36 students. The average level of student preparation in economics
was intermediate undergraduate micro- and macroeconomics, taught from standard
textbooks. Motivation was not a problem as the students were preparing for a
professional qualification and represented an elite group already. The module was
designed to introduce structuralist macroeconomic modeling techniques, specifically
stock-flow consistent macroeconomic modeling via simulation, also called the
‘structuralist’ approach (Taylor,00A0;2004, pg. 19), to the students, and these new
concepts and techniques were to be delivered using PBL methods. The canonical
PBL method has students and teachers confront an ill-structured problem that, as a
result of investigation, research, and cooperative discussion, allows for more than one
possible correct solution. As students work on the problem, they discover that
understanding economics concepts are essential to framing and solving the dilemma.
Problems, although loosely structured to allow for student discovery and
independent learning, contain a fixed set of components. My treatment was
different from this because there was really only one answer to the problem
statement—the answer that lead students to the model developed in lectures later
on.
Initially, students found the new teaching method difficult to cope with, and to a
certain extent the novelty in lecture structure retarded progress in content delivery
for the first few weeks. This ‘learner resistance’ is well documented in the PBl
literature (Schmidt and Moust,00A0;2000), though it represents a significant cost in
lecturing time lost. Once the ‘rules of the game’ had been learned though, in general
students found the module useful and stimulating. In a questionnaire distributed
during the last class, students rated the module highly relative to other modules
taken, though in the qualitative section of the questionnaire their comments showed
there was definite room for improvement in the module design, especially with regard
to the formation of groups, group size in particular, and feedback on problem
sets.
3 Issues in PBL setup and delivery
As in all PBL-based modules, each lecture began with a problem statement, the
lecturer gave the students access to the resources to try and solve the problem, with
the lecturer acting as a guide to these resources, solving simple conceptual blocks for
the students as the lecture progressed. The students worked through various
problem-based scenarios, using the internet and available informational resources as
guides, and reported the results of their problem-solving methods via weblogs
set up by each group. The lecture theatre had wireless access, so students
could work on their laptops in groups during the lecture. Each model was
simulated for the students using Eviews, and students were taken through the
estimation and simulation of the different models using different parameters,
situations, etc, in computer labs lead by a teaching assistant later on in the
week.
Teaching a complicated, technique-laden subject like structuralist macroeconomics
from a PBL standpoint also requires some modification of the textbook PBL premise.
In essence, there are no open ended answers that groups might come useful p
with—the correct answer is always the model to be taught in lectures. PBL
gave the students a clearer motivation for the development of these models,
and students could definitely see the rationale for developing these models
in a stock-flow consistent way, but in the end, the models still had to be
developed, discussed, solved for its steady state(s), shocked, and simulated.
This is the methodology of structuralist macroeconomics. The PBL method
allowed students to see why these methods were being chosen above other
neoclassical or neo-Keynesian alternatives, but the models still had to be
solved. So a blend of PBl and traditional lecturing and problem-sets was
required.
4 Module Design and Assessment
The module was designed around twelve two-hour lectures with the lecturer, followed
by one-hour tutorials and computer labs with a teaching assistant to embed the
concepts learned in the module for the students. The module began with an overview
of the differences between the stock-flow consistent (or structuralist) approach and
the traditional orthodox Neo-Keynesian approaches the students had previously been
exposed to. The differing philosophies of the two schools were presented, as well as
their respective policy prescriptions for dealing with the various macroeconomic
pathologies of inflation, unemployment, etc. Each subsequent lecture introduced
students to a new and successively more complex model of the macroeconomy using a
problem statement and in class exercises to guide student inquiry. The primary
learning objective of the module was to give students the tools to actually
create such models themselves using computer programs such as Eviews or
Mathematica.
To get a grade in the module, students had to complete all their problems and
submit them as a group online for 20%, produce and deliver a 30 minute presentation
and summary of a seminal paper in the area worth 30% of their grade, with the
intended audience being their peers in the class. Students were graded on the quality
of this presentation by the other groups with the lecturer having the final say in
grading. They were also required to complete a final written exam solving standard
models for 50%.
5 Conclusion: Student Feedback, and Lessons Learned
As a result of the continual assessment and large group size, as well as the high
quality of initial student preparation, no student failed the module in 2006. The most
interesting remarks are found in the qualitative comments. Some students feel
the PBL module is working well, writing “Lecturer is knowledgeable and
very enthusiastic about all aspects of economics. The module objectives
could be a little clearer.” However, others find the method confusing and
annoying “The lectures are not structured, there are no clear objectives and
it is very badly taught. The groups for projects are too bifg and the [sic]
self-based learning is not working.” The comments that appear most often is the
seeming lack of a clear objective in each lecture followed by group size. It is
reasonable from the student’s point of view that each lecture would look
unstructured: one does start out with a sentence and a set of web links, after all.
The issue of group size, 2-3 versus 4-5 students, came up over and over.
Because students were randomly allocated to rather large groups at the
start of the module there was some infighting and shirking, though this
was not reported until after the module had finished, and even then only
conversationally. The area of most contention was the presentation, where
students were asked to summarize a technical paper in such a way that
they could teach the paper to their peers. Those groups who by chance had
a more technically minded member or two seemed to shine, while other
groups did not fare so well, and this caused some friction in the class. The
next class will thus have students ‘self-selecting’ onto groups of between
2 and 3 at a maximum. While this increases the amount of work for the
lecturer, it also removes many of the issues that came up during this semester’s
module.
References
South-Western College Pub., 1st edition, 2007. URL http://www.amazon.com/Macroeconomics-Approach-Robert-J-Barro/dp/0324178107/ref=pd_bbs_sr_1?ie=UTF8&s=books&qid=1198791536&sr=1-1.
Growth. MIT Press, 2nd edition, 2003. URL http://www.amazon.com/Economic-Growth-2nd-Robert-Barro/dp/0262025531/ref=sr_1_1?ie=UTF8&s=books&qid=1198791876&sr=1-1.
Education, 20(1):481–486, 1986.
Delisle. How to use problem-based learning in the classroom. Association for
Supervision and Curriculum Development Alexandria, Virginia USA, 1997.
URL http://shop.ascd.org/productdisplay.cfm?productid=197166.
and Marc Lavoie. Monetary Economics An Integrated Approach to Credit,
Money, Income, Production and Wealth. Palgrave-Macmillan, 2006. URL http://www.palgrave.com/products/Catalogue.aspx?is=0230500552.
and Yolanda Bellisimo. Developing a problem-based learning simulation: An
economics unit on trade. Simulation and Gaming, 35(4):488–498, 2004.
John00A0;R. Mergendoller, and Yolanda Bellisimo. Problem-based learning
and high school macroeconomics: A comparative study of instructional
methods. Journal of Economic Education, 36(4):315–331, 2005. URL http://www.indiana.edu/~econed/issues/v36_4/1.htm.
learning: A review of research. In D.00A0;Evenson and C.00A0;Hmelo, editors,
Problem-based Learning: A Research Perspective on Learning Interactions.
London: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, 2000.
Confessions of a first-time user. New Directions for Teaching and Learning,
95:45–51, 2003. URL 10.1002/tl.112.
2004. URL http://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog/TAYREC.html.